Re-Evaluating a Core/Noncore Electric Market by mThink, May 23, 2005 It is difficult to discuss or propose a core/noncore market structure without discussing Californias previous retail market restructuring effort. Many academics and others have written papers pointing out the flaws in Californias previous actions. One aspect of those earlier restructuring debates deserves prominent treatment: customer choice. In the aftermath of the electricity crisis, we have given comparatively short shrift to customers served by Californias electric system. What do customers want? The short, anecdotal answer is that they want three things: lower prices, high-quality service and options (about where they buy their power and what type of power they buy). In numerous surveys, customers especially residential customers report that they would actually pay more for green power. Knowing this, it is fair to conclude that, in many instances, the current market structure is not serving the needs and wants of customers. To that end, a different core/noncore structure should be considered under which a 200-kW size threshold is set for customers being automatically defined as noncore, as long as aggregation is allowed and preconditions are in effect. Those include, primarily, mechanisms to guard against cost-shifting both of past costs and of future utility generation investments between so-called captive customers and those who opt for choice. Companies are risk-averse and long-term investment requires a stable environment that is dependent upon a considerable degree of certainty in the regulatory arena. For generation investment, merchant generators cannot get financing for investments without the guarantee of a multiyear power purchase agreement from a regulated utility, which in turn requires certainty of cost recovery from rate payers that can come only from the California Public Utilities Commission. Despite these uncertainties, we have greater certainty about other aspects of the system. Certain physical realities remain. There are chiefly two: first, load levels and load growth are fairly predictable, at least over the short and medium term. Regardless of who serves that load, it can be counted on to exist and grow, at a modest 2 percent or so at least, over the next several years. Second, the amount of electric generation available in the state today is measurable. Again, this is regardless of who actually owns the capacity or what entities are proposing to build new generation. So, it is possible to calculate, within reasonable bounds, what the electric supply and demand balance is likely to be over the next few years. Thus, what we are actually addressing with a core/noncore market structure is purely economic policy. We are struggling with how to allocate costs (and therefore risk) among a series of actors in the market: customers, utilities, generators, energy service providers and, for the last three, shareholders. Each of these actors would like to minimize their risk, and it is the job of regulators and legislators to balance that risk and ensure that it is shared. The key element, therefore, becomes the application of uniform resource adequacy requirements on all load-serving entities (LSEs) in the system. If all LSEs are required to have under contract sufficient capacity and energy to serve their customers, plus a reserve margin, there should be ample opportunity for investment and profit, while spreading the risk of reliability failure among a number of actors. One option for addressing this problem is the development of a capacity market. In meeting the resource adequacy requirements, LSEs should manage a diverse portfolio of types of resources as well as contract terms. There should be business risk for all LSEs, investor-owned utilities (IOUs) and energy service providers (ESPs) for prudent portfolio management. Cost Issues Utilities know the costs of their retained generation in the past and on an ongoing basis. The costs of the power contracts the state has with the Department of Water Resources are finite and the time period is fixed. Recent and future investment, either in the form of a physical asset or a contractual commitment, is also knowable. Legal and regulatory requirements exist, to one degree or another, that constrain our flexibility in allocating all of these costs. However, there could be other creative ways of assessing charges to cover these costs, without creating cost shifts or potential cost shifts among customers. The benefit of this new assessment structure would be greater customer choice at an earlier time period. Current and future investments in generation have the same potential to become future stranded costs. Thus, under any core/noncore model, we will need an ongoing mechanism to guard against cost shifting. Utilities argue that until their customer base is reasonably certain, they are unable to make long-term investments in generation. The same is likely true for ESPs. So, without certain entry and exit rules, no LSE is going to be willing to make long-term investments. The scenario that most observers are worried about is when an IOU invests in a long-term generation resource for a certain forecasted future load, and then loses that load to a direct access (or noncore) provider. In this situation, the concern is about remaining customers of the IOU being required to pick up the cost of the generation investment. In reality, if an IOU makes an investment that turns out not to be needed to serve its future retail load, the IOU will sell its excess generation on the wholesale market. If an ESP needs generation resources, it may buy the excess IOU generation. This gives rise to the worry that there could be a socalled death spiral, whereby IOUs invest in generation for a decreasing customer base; that customer base migrates to direct access or noncore status, forcing IOUs to sell their excess power at a loss on the wholesale market, finally leading to cost shifts to remaining IOU customers, and further incentive for noncore exit. In this situation, it is also important to keep in mind that the size of the potential cost shift, however, is not the full cost of the investment in generation by the IOU, but the difference between the wholesale market price and retail rates received by the IOU. This amount should be coverable by instituting reasonable market rules for switching and cost responsibility principles. Structuring a capacity market is another way to address this issue. In discussing this alternative proposal for core/noncore structure, the following principles are important to consider: Certainty of structure and rules is paramount; Cost causation; Rational rate design; Preserving reliability; Five-year planning horizons (supply and demand); Importance of aggregation as option; and Customer size threshold for noncore. Certainty It is a fairly obvious and often-made point that certainty of market rules promotes investment. Certainty, in this case, means not only a clear market structure, but also clear implementation rules and time frames. We need to establish a definition of which customers are core and are eligible for noncore; rules for switching from core to noncore status and back again need to be clear and stable; cost responsibility needs to be clear and calculable for customers making economic decisions. Cost Causation In general, customers should pay for generation costs incurred on their behalf. If an IOU makes a power plant investment while serving a particular noncore eligible customer, for example, that customer should be responsible for paying its fair share of the cost of that investment, even if it later elects service from an energy service provider. This, in effect, covers the revenue requirement of a generation investment. Rational Rate Design In addition to covering the revenue requirement, a wholesale effort is needed to rationalize the rate structures for many customer classes to reflect the true cost of serving those customers. Generally speaking, fixed costs should be assessed with a fixed charge, while variable costs should vary by usage levels. Moving toward real-time pricing and other tariff designs that allow rates to fluctuate with costs is not only a principle necessary for a functional core/noncore market structure, it is also likely to be a reasonable precondition. Preserving Reliability As discussed, any market structure change should occur only in the context of a stable resource adequacy requirement for all LSEs. If all entities serving customers in the market are required to prove resource adequacy, then the system in general should be resource adequate, regardless of which entity is serving a particular customer. This leads to a discussion of the provider of last resort issue. IOUs worry that no matter how the market rules are structured, if some unanticipated situation occurs and there is a system emergency, all customers will expect that they will be able to switch back to their IOU provider and be served. The IOUs should be the provider of last resort, but should be appropriately compensated for fulfilling that role. Planning Horizons Most customers in the market have a one- to two-year planning horizon, while most power plants cannot be built without at least a 10-year revenue stream. The need to bridge this gap exists both for IOUs and ESPs, since both want to be able to serve their customers at the lowest cost, which involves some long-term commitments. To balance the risk and allow for reasonable planning horizons, require a five-year commitment from customers to their core or noncore status. This would mean that customers wishing to become noncore would pay a cost responsibility surcharge for generation built or contracted for on their behalf while the IOU served them. Likewise, a noncore customer who made an initial five-year commitment to noncore status but wishes to switch back to the IOU, would have to pay the market rate for the remainder of the five-year commitment to noncore. Switching among non-IOU providers would not create additional cost responsibility, beyond the five-year commitment, but if there was any IOU service in the interim, the customer would pay the market rate. Aggregation Aggregation of customers under the noncore size threshold whatever it is finally resolved to be is of critical importance to satisfying customer needs. For a number of noncore customers, the advantages of noncore service will not be limited to price, but will include such important customer service options as innovative billing and metering services, more responsive customer service representatives or the ability to serve statewide chain stores through one provider. For example, a fast food chain with locations in all service territories could have one noncore ESP that provides aggregated billing to the corporate headquarters for all locations. No IOU can offer that service, by definition. Most fast food chains would not come close to meeting a 200 kW-per-month size threshold at each location/meter, but through aggregation, these types of customers needs can be served. Aggregation is also an important option for smaller customers wishing to choose green power options. Without allowance for small customer aggregation, retail ESPs with green portfolios would not be able to serve residential customers. Customer Size Threshold If aggregation is allowed, the size threshold required to achieve noncore status becomes less important. A 500-kW threshold for monthly peak demand would create an automatic noncore status only for the very largest big box retail stores and office buildings, plus most industrial customers. A 200-kW monthly peak demand threshold would capture a much larger portion of the commercial market. The CPUCs preference would be for a 200-kW threshold, although 500 kW would be satisfactory if aggregation of smaller customer loads is allowed. Meeting the needs of utilities, independent power producers and Wall Street is important, but should not be the primary function of the CPUC. We exist to ensure that customers are served. In implementing a core/noncore in the structure as outlined, we can give customers the choices they want and also meet the needs of California and its power providers and generators. Filed under: White Papers Tagged under: Utilities